[Short excerpt
from my submission to the European Commission in the context of its public
consultation on the evaluation of the consortia block exemption regulation].
Please cite
this document as:
Haralambides, H.E. (2019) "Gigantism
in Container Shipping, Ports and Global Logistics: A time-lapse into the future". Maritime Economics & Logistics, (21):1, pp 1-63, February 2019].
_________________
I have
often remarked that gigantism in
container shipping has been induced by both port competition and shipping alliances. Indeed, without
the possibility to use each other’s ships, no carrier by himself alone would be
able to achieve a capacity utilization
high enough to justify the use of present day mega-ships, while at the same
time offering the frequency that shippers require.
But
carriers have gone a step too far: At the time of writing, three alliances[1] carry
80% of global trade. Such consolidation, in an industry that is already highly
concentrated, is bound to finally
attract the scrutiny of the regulator who, with the final consumer in mind, is
likely to encourage more competition rather than further consolidation. If this
happens, i.e., if container shipping becomes more open and competitive in the
future, and if alliance agreements regarding vessel sharing,
investment planning, etc. are scrutinized more closely for their compatibility
with competition law, as I expect, the joint
filling of the ship will become more difficult and ship sizes shall by necessity decrease, together with an increase in the
number of ports of call. Low prices would then be achieved through more
competition rather than big ship sizes. This is
the more so when it is doubtful if the economies
of scale in shipping are passed on to the final consumer, as required by
the consortia block exception from
the provisions of competition law in Europe.
There are a number of macro-trends that, in
addition to the above, might advocate for smaller ships and more port calls;
particularly the latter. In a nutshell: (a) Transshipment costs and if they can
help it shippers prefer to have their goods as close to them as possible; (b) Consolidation and distribution use land infrastructure without paying full
costs for the private use of a public good; (c) The external costs of
hub-and-spoking (congestion; pollution; accidents) may at times be as high as
2% of European GDP.
I thus argue that
transshipment, warehousing and distribution don’t come cheap, as our enthusiasm
with logistics often assumes. It is good to keep this in mind and thus make
sure that the costs (internal and external) of logistics operations are paid in
full, including the costs of using public
infrastructure. The latter, because (to a large extent) infrastructure is no longer a public
good and thus the user-pays
principle should in principle apply.
[1] 2M: (MSC, Maersk, HMM); Ocean
Alliance: (CMA-CGM, Cosco Group, OOCL and Evergreen); and THE Alliance: (Hapag
Lloyd, NYK, Yang Ming, MOL, K-Line).
[2] Haralambides, H.E. (2000) ‘A
second scenario on the future of the hub-and-spoke system in liner shipping’.
Latin Ports and Shipping 2000 Conference, Lloyd’s List, 14-16 November 2000,
Miami, FL., USA.
No comments:
Post a Comment