If you ask an ocean carrier how big a port should be, he would
immediately tell you “as big as possible”. Apparently, he wouldn’t want to wait
even for a minute if he could help it, and we have well established that, at a
port capacity utilization of around 75%, congestion starts to set in. If
instead you ask the same question to a port manager, particularly one
responsible for the returns on his money, the answer would be “as small as
possible”. Obviously, he would love having ships queuing up outside his port,
like the good old times, if he could help it. As usual, both need to put some
water in their wine: the ship cannot wait, nor however can the port continue spending
taxpayer money so that the ship does not do so. This is
particularly so in increasingly commercial activities, such as those of transshipment
container terminals, whose impacts are not localized in the economies which have
borne the brunt of the investment, but are rather dissipated throughout the
supply chain, from the country of origin to the country of final
destination of the transported goods.
Big
ships impose substantial demands on port capacity: A 1 kilometer berth could host
3 panamax ships simultaneously before, but it can accommodate only 2 of the larger containerships of today. As call size is only moderately correlated with vessel size, i.e. as carriers demand more berth space without bringing, proportionately, more traffic to the port, it would make a lot of sense to think of a different, revenue-neutral, terminal charging system based on ship-dimensions rather than $/box. Moreover, OECD
and MEL have calculated that the average container, arriving on a larger ship,
takes more time to handle and store. In other words, port time per TEU is an
increasing function of ship size. The “supply chain” diseconomies of scale of larger ships, including their impact on shippers’ inventory costs, start
from the port (graph).
The situation is not helped much by the increasing
competition between neighboring ports aimed at stealing transshipment traffic
from each other. This is particularly worrying with publicly funded port investments.
Clearly there is a need for public policy intervention, at least in Europe which needs to harmonize public spending among its member states, as well as ensure free and fair competition among its ports. I hope
to see this taking effect in the forthcoming EU state aid guidelines which should
include, finally, indications on what is public port investment and what is
investment benefiting identifiable users who should in all honesty bear the
cost of its development and maintenance (user pays). HH
No comments:
Post a Comment